In search of a rupee liquidity framework – Part I
(The following appeared on CNBCTV18 online on April 1, 2019 - link below:
https://www.cnbctv18.com/views/why-india-badly-needs-a-rupee-liquidity-framework-part-i-2793251.htm )
https://www.cnbctv18.com/views/why-india-badly-needs-a-rupee-liquidity-framework-part-i-2793251.htm )
In search of a rupee
liquidity framework – Part I
For years now, different financial market participants and
regulators have all talked past each other on the subject of “rupee liquidity”.
Rupee liquidity is a lubricant for the economy that also impacts
foreign exchange markets, monetary policy transmission, and lending incentives
of financial institutions.
Given the critical role it plays in financial stability, we
need a comprehensive rupee liquidity framework that ties in with monetary,
currency and macroprudential policies.
To help build such a framework, in this piece, we examine
what “rupee liquidity” means to different stakeholders.
In the sequel to this piece, we will draw an inventory of tools
available to manage rupee liquidity and suggest a framework to determine which
tool to use under what circumstance.
The blind men and
the liquidity elephant
Different stakeholders such as the Reserve Bank of India
(RBI), banks, good borrowers and stressed borrowers often mean different things
when they speak of “rupee liquidity”.
The RBI viewpoint
The RBI has so far evaluated rupee liquidity by focusing on
the Weighted Average Call Rate (WACR) at which banks borrow and lend overnight funds
amongst themselves. Since WACR has largely been well-behaved and close to the
RBI policy rate for a while now, RBI has often struggled to appreciate why
markets constantly complain about rupee liquidity.
Banking liquidity
Before we come to the banker’s perspective of liquidity, let’s
understand what it means to say that the banking system is “short of liquidity”,
say by INR 1 tn.
As on date, the banking system holds deposits of about INR
125 tn. Banks need to keep 4% of this, or about INR 5 tn, with the RBI under
statutory Cash Reserve Ratio (CRR). They also need to hold government bonds of around
INR 31 tn for Statutory Liquidity Ratio (SLR) and Basel Liquidity Coverage
Ratio (LCR).
If the banking system is “short of liquidity” by INR 1 tn
today, that implies that before taking corrective action, the banking system expects
to end with only INR 3 tn as CRR with RBI, instead of the statutory INR 4 tn.
This isn’t a problem, because banks today also hold INR 34
tn of government bonds, INR 3 tn more than the statutory INR 31 tn required. They
can meet the CRR shortfall by effectively borrowing INR 1 tn from the RBI
against INR 1 tn of excess bonds, through short-term “repo” transactions.
This isn’t “lazy banking” where banks are borrowing from RBI
rather than raising customer deposits – systemic banking liquidity status is largely
determined by RBI using the many tools at its disposal. As a corollary, RBI
would simply not allow a situation where the banking system is simultaneously
short of CRR and has inadequate surplus bonds to fill the CRR shortfall.
Banks can raise funds via RBI repos at or close to the
policy repo rate. As a result, WACR is also usually close to the repo rate,
irrespective of the size of banking liquidity shortfall.
When bankers fret about liquidity, therefore, WACR is not
really their concern, nor is the fear that CRR might not be met.
Banker’s
perspective on liquidity
The liquidity concern for banks is largely around asset-liability
mismatches.
Running a “negative asset-liability gap”, or using
short-term deposits to fund long-term loans, involves the liquidity risk that funds
may not be available to the bank when its deposits mature. There are strict regulatory
limits on the liquidity gaps that banks can run.
Market rates such as WACR or bond yields are simply irrelevant
to such liquidity risks.
Lending banks are constantly looking for durable deposits,
so that they can lend to their clients without breaching liquidity limits.
Over the past few years, banks have struggled to raise
adequate durable deposits.
For one, clients can obtain better tax-adjusted returns from
mutual funds and small saving schemes, than from bank term deposits. While funds
placed with any financial institution eventually flow into the banking system, these
are not as durable for individual banks as regular bank deposits.
In addition, regulatory liquidity risk limits such as Basel LCR
have been tightened over the years. This has left the banking system requiring
more durable deposits than ever before.
In this context, having a persistent banking liquidity shortage
transmits higher interest rates.
Consider a large private sector bank that currently offers
7.40% for durable 1-year fixed deposits and holds surplus 1-year government
T-bills yielding 6.40%. If it is also constantly short of CRR, it would much
rather sell the T-bill and effectively release 1-year money at 6.40%, rather
than continuously raise overnight money at the repo rate.
In summary, under consistent banking liquidity shortfall, individual
banks would focus on raising deposits and selling bonds, rather than raising
short-term repo funds or giving out term loans. This would keep term yields high across bonds,
deposits and loans.
The good borrower’s
perspective – where’s my rate cut?
When good quality borrowers bemoan liquidity, they usually
refer to high borrowing costs.
Transmission of lower rates can be helped by surplus systemic
banking liquidity.
In today’s context, if the banking system ended with a CRR balance
of INR 5 tn against the statutory requirement of INR 4 tn, banks would have to
dump the excess INR 1 tn with the RBI by way of a reverse repo, at a very low rate
of 6%.
Individual banks would then rather buy 3-month government T-bills
at 6.3%, or give loans to clients at higher yields, than lend overnight money to
the RBI at the 6.0% reverse repo.
In summary, keeping the banking system in constant liquidity
surplus, even by a small amount, is a powerful carrot to incentivize individual
banks to buy bonds, give loans, and ensure transmission of lower rates,
consistent with an accommodative monetary stance.
Conversely, as described earlier, keeping the banking system
liquidity consistently short is a good stick to force banks to raise lending
rates, consistent with a tight monetary stance.
In essence, the banking liquidity status is a powerful
transmission adjunct to the MPC’s monetary stance.
The stressed
borrower’s perspective – water, water everywhere
Finally, when stressed borrowers refer to liquidity problems,
their real issue revolves around their credit worthiness.
In fact, trying to address funding for stressed sectors by
infusing surplus banking liquidity can be downright dangerous.
As discussed, a consistent banking liquidity surplus is a
powerful carrot for banks to give customer loans. If this collective chase for
assets and yields leads to systemwide compromises on credit and risk standards,
we could severely risk financial stability.
In the short run, banking liquidity can be an expedient palliative
for credit stresses. But such palliatives at best help kick the can down the
road. Unless accompanied by tougher, deeper correctives such as asset
restructuring, policy reform and asset recapitalization, surplus liquidity
alone can eventually lead to even more severe financial instability.
Looking ahead
The RBI has multiple tools to manage overall banking
liquidity. In Part II of this piece tomorrow, we will catalog the various
tools, the duration of their impact, and their inevitable side-effects. We will
then suggest a framework to help determine the liquidity needs of the system
and choose the right mix of tools to achieve this with acceptable
side-effects.
Comments
Post a Comment