India's Monetary Policy Framework - Rituals and Lion Tamers
(The following article appeared on CNBC TV18 online, link per below:
https://www.cnbctv18.com/finance/rbi-rbi-monetary-policy-mpc-inflatio-repo-rate-the-monetary-policy-framework-of-rituals-and-lion-tamers-rbi-rbi-monetary-policy-mpc-inflation-repo-rate-3560261.htm )
https://www.cnbctv18.com/finance/rbi-rbi-monetary-policy-mpc-inflatio-repo-rate-the-monetary-policy-framework-of-rituals-and-lion-tamers-rbi-rbi-monetary-policy-mpc-inflation-repo-rate-3560261.htm )
The Monetary Policy Framework – Of Rituals & Lion Tamers
Over the next few days, the bimonthly monetary policy ritual
will play out. Our brightest economic minds – including the six high priests of
the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC) - will first hazard where Consumer Price
Index (CPI) inflation and GDP growth are headed. Interspersed with mantras such
as output gap, exogenous and endogenous factors, core and headline inflation
and suchlike, they will then suggest the appropriate policy interest rate
action to keep CPI inflation in check, while fostering growth.
If we step back, however, there is much to ponder. Does the
MPC framework really work the way one would expect? Are we adequately debating all
the critical financial stability issues linked to monetary policy?
Of crystal balls…
Truth is, with 57% of CPI directly dependent on food and
fuel prices, we should have very little confidence around any 1-year ahead CPI inflation
estimates.
In April 2018, for example, the MPC had projected CPI at
4.4% for H2 FY19 with an upward bias.
As it turned out, inflation averaged 2.5% during the period.
Given monetary policy prescriptions are based on projected inflation,
the starting point itself is shaky.
…and faith healing
Weak inflation projections are the least of our problems. Let’s
now ask a taboo monetary question.
Even if we estimated inflationary risks, say by accurately gauging
inflation expectations, are we sure we can control CPI inflation by using
policy interest rates?
Here’s how textbook monetary policy works. A hike in policy
interest rate increases cost of funds, reduces borrowings, reduces consumption
demand backed by borrowings, and hence brings down consumer inflation.
This makes intuitive sense in a borrow-to-spend economy like
the US, where CEIC data shows household debt at 66% of GDP.
How would it work in a borrow-to-produce economy like India,
where household debt is only 11% of GDP, and where private non-household debt –
i.e., borrowings towards production and investment, rather than consumption –
is five times household debt?
Is it possible that interest rates are a net input cost in the
Indian context? This existential monetary question is yet to be even acknowledged
by economists, let alone addressed.
To bristling monetarists, this is not to suggest – as
Erdogan does - that the path to lower inflation is lower interest rates. Far
from it. But we do need a far deeper understanding of how monetary policy works
in India.
Until then, the MPC process risks being reduced to a ritual
based on intense faith, rather than cold logic.
But the framework has
worked, hasn’t it?
CPI inflation has come down sharply from 8.60% when the current
framework was suggested in January 2014, to 2.92% now. Should we not give some
credit to the framework?
Here is a classic trap that my old professor warned of. Whiskey
and soda intoxicate John, gin and soda intoxicate John, vodka and soda intoxicate
John, ergo, soda intoxicates John.
As a parallel, low food prices and the framework brought
down inflation, low crude oil prices and the framework brought down inflation, favorable
external context and the framework brought down inflation, therefore, has the
framework brought down inflation?
Beyond these admittedly flippant observations, of course, we
need sift through the evidence.
What the evidence suggests
The evidence from research is far from conclusive.
Mishra, Sengupta and Montiel (2016) found that tight
monetary policy tends to marginally increase
inflation in India.
Chinoy, Kumar and Mishra (2016) found that the disinflation
between 2014-16 was largely caused by moderation of inflation expectations and
lower food prices. However, there is little to suggest that the new framework is
behind lower inflation expectations in India – how many of our producers and
consumers are even aware of the policy repo rate?
The monetary
framework as the lion tamer
This is not to suggest that the monetary framework is completely
flawed. We have to understand the genesis of this framework, and therefore how
it could actually work.
Between 2009-2013, our fiscal and external balance steadily
worsened. Our monetary policy was then like a deer caught in the headlights –
frozen by doubts if it could, or should, address the myriad issues around
currency markets, growth, inflation and financial stability.
With monetary authorities confused, it was easy to push for the
punch bowl of monetary accommodation. Between April 2012 and May 2013, policy
repo rate was brought down from 8.50% to 7.25%. During FY13, the RBI purchased
30% of the net government bond issuance through bond open market operations
(OMOs). Finally, the bubble burst in mid-2013, with the fed taper tantrum as
the proximate trigger.
The current monetary policy framework of using policy rates
to control CPI can perhaps tame the lion that can truly impact financial
stability – the government. It promises that if the government does its bit to control
food prices and fiscal balance, it will be rewarded with lower interest rates –
else, it should beware of the whip of higher rates.
Perhaps the framework goaded the government to controlling
food prices the past five years (some would argue too successfully), and the
fiscal deficit at least during FY14 – FY17.
If this prognosis is right, we could ignore much of the economist
speak around CPI and policy rates, and instead focus on core issues of fiscal
balance, food prices, monetary transmission, external balance and
macroprudential stability.
The fiscal lion is
breaking loose
The fiscal lion is breaking loose, and the lion tamer is so
far looking the other way.
Provisional data for FY19 shows that tax collections were
0.9% of GDP below revised estimates. Despite that, the government says it kept
FY19 fiscal deficit at 3.4% of GDP.
For anyone who cares to look, the government has simply
avoided paying some of its bills. Under its cash accounting methodology, if a
bill isn’t paid, there’s no expenditure to be recognized.
Here are some examples. Food Corporation of India has
outstanding debt of INR 1.96 lakh crores, in lieu of food subsidy due from the
government. Various other government owned entities have INR 0.88 lakh crores
of Government of India (GOI) serviced bonds outstanding, in lieu of government payments.
The debt of power distribution companies is expected to top INR 2.6 lakh crores
by end FY20.
Much of these hidden items are revenue expenditures, rather
than capital investments. If the government keeps its promises of lowering
taxes and increasing spending, we risk even higher revenue deficits.
With revenue deficits, we are borrowing off our children,
not for them.
The MPC, so far, has not acknowledged any of this.
Here are a few suggestions. First, closing our eyes may not
be the best way to debate the fiscal question. Second, while the very low CPI
inflation gives us much comfort, we need an informed debate around how much
fiscal space we really have, in the context of financial stability. We have
seen the consequences of simultaneously stretched fiscal and external balances
in the past – how do we ensure that this time is different? Third, we need to
revive the debate around quality of fiscal spending – the question of keeping
revenue deficits under control.
Liquidity management
& transmission
As the government brought down inflation from 2014 onwards,
the RBI brought down policy repo rates from 8% in December 2014 to 6.5% in
April 2016. However, end borrowing rates for clients barely moved. While there
are many reasons behind this, one area that the RBI simply hasn’t grasped is
the role of banking liquidity in monetary transmission.
We have argued earlier that banking liquidity surplus/
deficit is a powerful adjunct to transmit accommodative/ tight monetary policy
stance respectively. Dr. Rajan finally acknowledged this in the April 2016
policy, when he agreed to move banking liquidity to neutrality.
But we still need a coherent liquidity framework that ties
in with the monetary framework.
In addition, it is unclear how the RBI chooses from amongst
the many tools to manage Rupee liquidity. RBI purchased a staggering 67% of the
net GOI issuance in FY19 to infuse liquidity. Ironically, the 2014 Urjit Patel
report lamented the 30% of net GOI issuance purchased by RBI in FY13.
As we have also argued separately, we need a framework that helps
choose the appropriate instruments to manage liquidity under different
circumstances.
The impossible
trinity and external balance
Monetary policy and interest rates impact our external
balance much more than the current framework acknowledges.
In fact, we would argue that the new monetary policy
framework and poor monetary transmission was at least partly responsible for
the overvaluation of the Rupee till early 2018, and the sharp rise in open
currency exposures in the system.
This is a separate topic by itself – but in essence, we
believe that until the monetary framework better incorporates and debates the
external sector, it is dangerously incomplete.
Monetary policy,
reforms and macroprudential stability
In the Indian context, unfortunately, monetary policy is
sometimes expected to play a role in lieu of real reforms, or to mask inadequate
macroprudential controls. Consider the current situation around Non-Bank
Financial Companies (NBFCs).
There is a trust deficit around NBFCs. The way to eventually
address this is to undertake hard reform – improve governance and disclosures,
infuse capital, improve financial infrastructure, and conduct strict and
independent asset quality reviews. It is convenient for the market to brush
these hard steps aside and clamor for monetary easing as the first – and
perhaps only – line of defense.
On the flip side, concerns that the financial services
ecosystem cannot be trusted to deploy money safely should not come in the way
of the RBI easing interest rates and liquidity. Such concerns have to be addressed
through robust regulations and supervision, not by withholding monetary
responses.
Summary
The underpinnings of the MPC framework – inflation control
through the use of policy interest rates – may well be articles of faith in the
Indian context. However, as a means to control the government – arguably the
one entity that can most impact inflation and growth – the framework can have a
powerful role to play.
The true debate around monetary policy therefore has to
progress beyond CPI and policy rates, to financial stability discussions around
fiscal balance, external balance, and health of the financial services
ecosystem.
In the current context, we need a richer and more honest
debate around the extent and quality of our fiscal balance.
The monetary framework also has to acknowledge and debate
its impact on the external sector better.
The framework has not resolved the question of monetary
transmission. We need to incorporate a liquidity framework and debate the
appropriate liquidity tools to be used under different circumstances.
Finally, monetary action cannot substitute for hard, real
reform. On the flip side, inadequate prudential regulations and financial
supervision should not come in the way of appropriate monetary action.
Hey, thanks for the information. your posts are informative and useful. I am regularly following your posts.
ReplyDeleteRBL Bank,
Kotak Institutional Equities,
YES Securities,
The great thing about this post is quality information. I always like to read amazingly useful and quality content. Your article is amazing, thank you for sharing this article.
ReplyDeleteBambino Agro Industries Limited
Bampsl Securities Limited
Banaras Beads Limited
Banas Finance Limited